Discrete-Time Finance
\[ \def\BB#1{{\mathbb{#1}}} \def\BF#1{{\mathbf{#1}}} \]
yedlu, Winter 2024
Modeling evolutions of a variable is at the center of economic disciplines. We will first try to see tools we can use in discrete times and then push them forward in continuous times.
Linear Difference Equations
Consider the following evolution:
\[\begin{aligned} y_t &= a + b y_{t-1} \end{aligned}\]
with \(y_0\) being a pre-determined constant.
Then, we can iterate this over discrete times:
\[\begin{aligned} y_1 &= a + b y_0 \\ y_2 &= a + b y_1 = a + ba + b y_0 \\ y_3 &= a + b y_2 = a + ba + b^2 a + b^3 y_0 \\ & ... \\ y_t &= a (\sum_{i=0}^{t-1} b^i) + b^t y_0 \end{aligned}\]
We can further derive the geometric sum:
\[\begin{aligned} y_t &= a (\sum_{i=0}^{t-1} b^i) + b^t y_0 \\ &= a (\frac{1 - b^t}{1 - b}) + b^t y_0 \end{aligned}\]
Convergence
This condition
\[\begin{aligned} \lim_{t \to \infty} \frac{1 - b^t}{1 - b} = c, \quad c \in \BB{R} \end{aligned}\]
would be true if
\[\begin{aligned} \lim_{t \to \infty} b^t &= 0 \\ \implies \mid b \mid &< 1 \end{aligned}\]
In financial models we would typically assume the convergence is monotonic:
\(b \in (0,1)\).
Nevertheless, alternating convergence might be useful in some cases:
\(b \in (-1,0)\).
Solution
Assuming convergence, the steady-state of \(y_t\) would then be:
\[\begin{aligned} \overline{y} &= \lim_{t \to \infty} = a (\frac{1 - b^t}{1 - b}) + b^t y_0 \\ &= \frac{a}{1-b} \end{aligned}\]
Another way to find the steady state is to assume existance of \(\overline{y}\):
\[\begin{aligned} \overline{y} &= a + b \overline{y} \\ \implies \overline{y} &= \frac{a}{1-b} \end{aligned}\]
Exponential Growth
The general solution
\[\begin{aligned}
y_t &= \overline{y} + b^t (y_0 - \overline{y})
\end{aligned}\] tells us a story. The discrete-time process begins at \(y_0\), converges to \(\overline{y}\) in the end exponentially (\(b^t\)).
Transversality: Dividend Discount Revisited
We know that the price of a stock can be denoted by the dividend discount model:
\[\begin{aligned} p_t &= \frac{d_{t+1}}{1 + r} + \frac{d_{t+2}}{(1 + r)^2} + ... + \frac{d_{t+n}}{(1 + r)^n} + \frac{p_{t+n}}{(1 + r)^n} \end{aligned}\]
If we were to allow the time period goes to infinity:
\[\begin{aligned}
p_t &= \sum_{i = 1}^{n} \frac{d_{t+i}}{(1 + r)^i} + \lim_{n \to \infty} \frac{p_{t+n}}{(1 + r)^n}
\end{aligned}\]
We can then see that the following assumption makes the price of the stock to be unique (transversality condition):
\[\begin{aligned}
\lim_{n \to \infty} \frac{p_{t+n}}{(1 + r)^n} &= 0
\end{aligned}\]
If this term explodes, we would not be able to obtain a unique price for this stock.
This would be an interesting concept in Asset Pricing called market completeness.